💰Intro to Mathematical Economics Unit 9 – Probability Theory & Expected Utility

Probability theory and expected utility form the backbone of decision-making under uncertainty in economics. These concepts provide tools to quantify risk, model preferences, and analyze strategic interactions. They're essential for understanding everything from individual choices to market behavior. Applications range from portfolio optimization in finance to game theory in strategic decision-making. While these models offer powerful insights, they also have limitations. Real-world behavior often deviates from theoretical predictions, highlighting the need for nuanced interpretation and ongoing research.

Key Concepts

  • Probability theory provides a mathematical framework for quantifying and analyzing uncertainty
  • Random variables assign numerical values to outcomes of random experiments
  • Probability distributions describe the likelihood of different values of a random variable
  • Expected value represents the average outcome of a random variable over many repetitions
  • Variance measures the spread or dispersion of a random variable around its expected value
  • Utility theory models decision-making preferences and risk attitudes of individuals
  • Von Neumann-Morgenstern utility theorem establishes a framework for rational decision-making under uncertainty
  • Applications of probability and utility theory in economics include game theory, finance, and insurance

Probability Basics

  • Probability is a measure of the likelihood of an event occurring, expressed as a number between 0 and 1
    • 0 represents an impossible event, while 1 represents a certain event
  • Sample space is the set of all possible outcomes of a random experiment
  • Events are subsets of the sample space, representing specific outcomes or combinations of outcomes
  • Probability of an event A is denoted as P(A) and can be calculated using the following methods:
    • Classical approach: P(A) = (number of favorable outcomes) / (total number of possible outcomes)
    • Empirical approach: P(A) = (frequency of event A) / (total number of trials)
  • Conditional probability P(A|B) measures the probability of event A occurring given that event B has occurred
  • Independent events have probabilities that do not depend on the occurrence of other events
    • For independent events A and B, P(A and B) = P(A) × P(B)

Random Variables and Distributions

  • A random variable is a function that assigns a numerical value to each outcome in a sample space
  • Discrete random variables take on a countable number of distinct values (integers)
    • Examples include the number of defective items in a production batch or the number of customers in a queue
  • Continuous random variables can take on any value within a specified range (real numbers)
    • Examples include the weight of a randomly selected product or the time until a machine fails
  • Probability mass function (PMF) describes the probability distribution of a discrete random variable
    • PMF gives the probability of each possible value of the random variable
  • Probability density function (PDF) describes the probability distribution of a continuous random variable
    • PDF gives the relative likelihood of the random variable taking on a specific value
  • Cumulative distribution function (CDF) gives the probability that a random variable is less than or equal to a given value
    • CDF is defined for both discrete and continuous random variables

Expected Value and Variance

  • Expected value (or mean) of a random variable X, denoted as E(X), is the weighted average of all possible values
    • For discrete random variables: E(X)=xxP(X=x)E(X) = \sum_{x} x \cdot P(X = x)
    • For continuous random variables: E(X)=xf(x)dxE(X) = \int_{-\infty}^{\infty} x \cdot f(x) dx
  • Linearity of expectation states that for random variables X and Y: E(X+Y)=E(X)+E(Y)E(X + Y) = E(X) + E(Y)
  • Variance, denoted as Var(X) or σ2\sigma^2, measures the average squared deviation from the mean
    • Var(X)=E[(XE(X))2]=E(X2)[E(X)]2Var(X) = E[(X - E(X))^2] = E(X^2) - [E(X)]^2
  • Standard deviation σ\sigma is the square root of the variance and has the same units as the random variable
  • Chebyshev's inequality provides a bound on the probability of a random variable deviating from its mean
    • For any k > 0: P(XE(X)kσ)1k2P(|X - E(X)| \geq k\sigma) \leq \frac{1}{k^2}

Utility Theory

  • Utility is a measure of satisfaction or preference that an individual derives from consuming goods or services
  • Cardinal utility assigns numerical values to represent the level of satisfaction
    • Allows for interpersonal comparisons of utility
  • Ordinal utility ranks preferences without assigning specific numerical values
    • Only the relative ordering of preferences matters
  • Utility functions U(x) map the consumption of goods or wealth levels to utility values
    • Monotonicity: more is preferred to less, so utility functions are non-decreasing
  • Marginal utility is the additional satisfaction gained from consuming one more unit of a good
    • Diminishing marginal utility: the additional satisfaction decreases as more units are consumed
  • Risk attitudes describe an individual's preferences for uncertain outcomes
    • Risk-averse individuals prefer a certain outcome to a risky one with the same expected value
    • Risk-neutral individuals are indifferent between a certain outcome and a risky one with the same expected value
    • Risk-seeking individuals prefer a risky outcome to a certain one with the same expected value

Decision Making Under Uncertainty

  • Von Neumann-Morgenstern (VNM) utility theorem provides a foundation for decision-making under uncertainty
    • Axioms: completeness, transitivity, continuity, and independence
  • Expected utility theory states that a rational decision-maker chooses the option with the highest expected utility
    • Expected utility of an option: EU=ipiU(xi)EU = \sum_{i} p_i \cdot U(x_i), where pip_i is the probability of outcome xix_i
  • Certainty equivalent is the guaranteed amount that provides the same utility as a risky option
  • Risk premium is the difference between the expected value of a risky option and its certainty equivalent
    • Measures the amount an individual is willing to pay to avoid risk
  • Allais paradox demonstrates violations of the independence axiom in the VNM utility theorem
    • Highlights the limitations of expected utility theory in describing actual human behavior

Applications in Economics

  • Game theory models strategic interactions between decision-makers
    • Players' payoffs are represented by utility functions
    • Nash equilibrium: a set of strategies where no player can improve their expected utility by unilaterally changing strategy
  • Portfolio theory in finance uses probability and utility to optimize investment decisions
    • Mean-variance analysis balances the expected return and risk (variance) of a portfolio
    • Efficient frontier represents the set of portfolios with the highest expected return for a given level of risk
  • Insurance markets rely on probability theory to calculate premiums and manage risk
    • Law of large numbers ensures the long-run stability of insurance companies
    • Adverse selection and moral hazard are key challenges in insurance markets
  • Auction theory applies probability and utility to design and analyze auction mechanisms
    • Different auction formats (first-price, second-price, all-pay) lead to different bidding strategies and outcomes

Common Pitfalls and Misconceptions

  • Gambler's fallacy: believing that past events influence the probability of future independent events
    • Example: thinking that a coin is "due" for heads after a series of tails
  • Confusion between correlation and causation
    • Correlation does not imply a causal relationship between variables
  • Neglecting base rates when evaluating conditional probabilities
    • Base rate fallacy: focusing on specific information and ignoring the underlying probability of an event
  • Misinterpreting the meaning of expected value
    • Expected value is a long-run average, not a guaranteed outcome
  • Assuming that all individuals have the same risk preferences
    • Risk attitudes can vary significantly between individuals and contexts
  • Overreliance on expected utility theory to describe real-world decision-making
    • Behavioral economics highlights systematic deviations from the predictions of expected utility theory


© 2024 Fiveable Inc. All rights reserved.
AP® and SAT® are trademarks registered by the College Board, which is not affiliated with, and does not endorse this website.

© 2024 Fiveable Inc. All rights reserved.
AP® and SAT® are trademarks registered by the College Board, which is not affiliated with, and does not endorse this website.